Background

Trust: No Economy, Money, Business Without It

Uploaded 3/23/2023, approx. 17 minute read

My name is Sam Vaknin. I served as economic advisor to several governments around the world for almost three decades. I worked with multinationals as financial advisor. I've collaborated with multilateral institutions such as the IMF and the World Bank.

Based on all this experience and the observations I've made, I would like to discuss with you today the issue of trust in economics.


On my other main channel, Sam Vaknin, on YouTube, I just posted a video which deals with trust in interpersonal relationships. In that video, I've analyzed the psychology of trust. So actually the two go together, they're complementary pieces.

But this particular part, this particular video, deals with economics. Economics acquired its dismal reputation by pretending to be an exact science rather than a branch of mass psychology.

Yes, granted, there is behavioral economics. But even behavioral economics is not going far enough.

There's no admitting among economists, even behavioral economists, that economics is 100% a branch of psychology.

In truth, it is a narrative struggling to describe the aggregate behavior of human beings. It seeks to cloak its uncertainties and shifting fashions with mathematical formulae and elaborate econometric computerized models. It's not working too well.

So much is certain, though, that people operate within markets. These markets are free, these markets are regulated, they're patchy, they're organized, they're numerous types of markets.

But people work within markets. People attach numerical and emotional values to their inputs, work, capital. And similarly, they attach values to their possessions, their assets, their natural endowments.

People communicate these values to each other by sending out signals. And these signals are known as prices.

Prices are signals about the value that people attach to various things.

There's a famous saying that the cynic knows the price of everything and the value of nothing.

This distinction is a bit artificial.

Yet, these entire edifice, the market, and its price and signaling mechanisms, they critically depend on a psychological fact.

And this is trust. If people do not trust each other, if people do not trust the economic envelope within which they interact, preemptive mistrust, if there is a lack of trust or pervasive lack of trust, permeating, ambient, economic activity gradually grinds to hold.

There is a strong correlation between the general level of trust and the extent and intensity of economic activity.

Francis Fukuyama, the political scientist, distinguishes between high-trust and prosperous societies and low-trust and therefore impoverished collectives.

Trust underlies economic success, he argued already in 1995.

But there's a problem with that. Like every psychological extensive trait, it's not a monolithic quantity.

There are a few categories of economic trust.

Some forms of trust are akin to a public good and they are closely related to governmental action or inaction. The reputation of the state and its institutions, the pronounced agenda of the government, they all determine, to a large extent, trust.

Because the government has become a huge part of modern economies.

Other types of trust are the outcomes of kinship, tribal, ethnic origin, personal standing, goodwill, reputation, corporate runs and other data generated by individuals, households and firms. They are data-related trust.

Such information creates two types of output, reinforced trust, where behavior matches expectations, and inductive distrust, where behavior frustrates expectations.

Sothere we have kind of two processes.

Sometimes we behave so that our behavior reflects expectations, enhances them and realizes them in many cases.

Sometimes, and this is what I call reinforced trust, and sometimes our behavior frustrates expectations, diminishes them, negates them, challenges them, undermines them or even vitiates them. This is what I call inductive distrust.


Let's start with the various types of trust.

The most basic foundational trust is trust in the playing field.

To transact, people have to maintain faith in a relevant economic horizon and in the immutability of the economic playing field or envelope.

Put less obscurely, a few hidden assumptions underlie the continued economic activity of market players.

Market players, for example, assume, or agents assume, that the market will continue to exist. It's a very simple assumption.

In the foreseeable future, the market will continue to exist in its current form. It will remain inert, unhindered by externalities and external shocks like government intervention, geopolitical upheavals, pandemics, crisis, abrupt changes in accounting policies and tax laws, hyperinflation, institutional and structural reform, and other market deflecting events and processes.

This projection, this extrapolation of the market, is of course counterfactual. Markets are very often subject to external shocks. This would explain the dynamic of bubbles and busts.

Because bubbles are founded, fundamentally, they are extensions of the extrapolation.

Without this extrapolation, there would be no bubbles.

The belief that future market players operating in identical markets would absorb the current supply. Its yields lead to bubbles and busts is when reality testing is restored and there are external shocks, regulation, taxation, pandemics, crisis, wars, etc.

Market players assume that their price signals will not be distorted or thwarted constantly. The market signals will not be interfered with or interrupted. There will be no intervention skewing the efficient and rational allocation of risks and rewards.

So things like insider trading, stock manipulation, monopolies, cartels, trusts, informal economic activities like the black market or the grey market, hoarding, all these tend to consistently but unpredictably distort pricing.

And so they deter market participation.

The market, the liquidity dries up. Market players take for granted the existence and continuous operation of institutions, financial intermediaries like banks, insurance companies, law enforcement agencies, courts, civil service, educational institutions and so on and so forth.

It is important to note that market players prefer continuity and certainty to evolution, however gradual, however ultimately beneficial.

A vinyl bureaucrat, a corrupt politician, is a known quantity, can be tackled effectively. The cost is known, the transaction cost. A period of transition to good and equitable governance can be more stifling, more damaging than any level of corruption and malfeasance.

And this is why economic activity drops sharply whenever institutions are being reformed.

Witness the transition from communism to capitalism in Eastern Europe and in the former republics of the USSR.


The second type of trust is trust in other players.

Market players assume that other players are generally benign, rational, that they have intentions, they're intentional, that they intend to maximize their benefits, that they're likely to act on their intentions in a legal, rule-based, rational manner.

This has been challenged by the School of Behavioral Economics, Kahneman, etc.

I'm not going to eat right now, but this is an underlying sort of assumption.

You can trust others.

Then there's trust in market liquidity.

By the way, the second type of trust, it leads to phenomena like World.com and Bernie Madoff and so on. These con artists leverage this type of trust.

And I encourage you to watch the video about the psychology of trust in my other channel.

Then there's trust in market liquidity.

When players assume that other players possess or have access to, the liquid means that they need in order to act on their intentions and obligations.

They know, from personal experience, that idle capital tends to dwindle and that the only way to perhaps maintain or increase the capital is to transact with others directly or through intermediaries, such as banks.

So they trust that liquidity will never remain hidden, obscured, under the mattress, but we're always exit, we're always out in order to participate in market activities so as to grow.

Then there is trust in other people's knowledge and ability. Market players assume that other players possess or have access to the intellectual property, the technology and the knowledge that they need in order to realize their intentions and obligations.

This implicitly presupposes that all other market players are physically, mentally, legally and financially able, competent and willing to act their parts as stipulated, for instance, in contracts they sign.

The emotional dimensions of contracting are often neglected in economics.

Players assume that their counterparts maintain a realistic and stable sense of self-worth based on intimate knowledge of their own strengths and weaknesses.

Self-awareness is critical. Market participants are presumed to harbor realistic expectations, commensurate with their skills and accomplishments.

Fake it till you make it is a very bad foundation for any market.

Allowance is made for exaggeration, of course. We all know that there is disinformation, even outright deception, but these are supposed to be fringe phenomena, very rare.

They can't become the founding principle.

And gradually, in today's modern economies, we are, we regrettablyare moving in that direction.

Fake it till you make it, have become an operating and organizing principle.

When trust breaks down, often the result of an external or internal systemic shock, people react as expected.

The number of voluntary interactions and transactions decreases sharply.

With a collapsed investment horizon, individuals and firms become corrupt in an effort to shortcut their way into economic benefits because they don't know how long will the system survive.

The short horizon, criminal activity increases. People compensate with this market failure. People compensate with fantasies and grandiose delusions for their growing sense of helplessness and certainty, fears.

This is a self-reinforcing mechanism. It's a vicious cycle which results in underconfidence and fluctuating self-esteem.

I mean, people develop psychological defenses, pronounced psychological defenses. They act out very often.

Cognitive dissonance begins to rain. People say, "I really choose to be poor," rather than, for example, heartless or ruthless.

There's pathological envy. People seek to deprive other people of their possessions and achievements and assets, and this way gain emotional reward.

Relative positioning becomes paramount and predominant. You can see this in social media, where people compare their popularity with others.

There's rigidity that sets you. "I'm like that. My family or ethnic group has been like that for generations. There's nothing I can or am willing to do."

Then there's passive-aggressive behavior, obstructing the workflow, absenteeism, stealing from the employer, and besting, adhering strictly to arcane regulations.

These are all reactions. These are all dysfunctional reactions to a breakdown in one or more of the four aforementioned types of trust.

When trust breaks down, there is something called anomie. M.L. Dokheim described it in his work.

Anomic societies, anonomic institutions, anonomic economies, they create dysfunctional, counterproductiveand antisocial behavior.

In a trust crisis, people are unable to postpone gratification. They often become frustrated, aggressive, deceitful if they're denied.

They resort to reckless behavior and to stop-gap economic activities. In economic environments with compromised and impaired trust, loyalty decreases and mobility increases.

People switch jobs. People renege on obligations. They fail to repay debts. They relocate often.

Concepts like exclusivity, sanctity of contracts, workplace loyalty, career path, all these get eroded and become meaningless.

As a result, little is invested in the future, in the acquisitions of skills, in long-term savings.

Short-termism, bottom-of-line mentality rule the day, and you have many get-rich-quick schemes.

The outcomes of a crisis of trust are usually catastrophic. Economic activity is much reduced.

Human capital is corroded and wasted. Brain drain increases. Illegal and extralegal activities rise.

Society is polarized between halves and halves not. Inter-ethnic and interracial tensions increase. To rebuild trust in such circumstances is a daunting task.

The loss of trust is contagious. Finally, it infects every institution, every profession in the land. It is the stuff that revolutions are made of.

I've designed a very simple index of trust and distrust. It has the following variables.

Each of these variables is scored on a scale of 1 to 10. So the formula is T, I, equals P plus L plus C plus I plus S plus M plus V plus F plus R plus W.

And I will explain each one of these shortly.

The index can range, of course, from 0 to 100, with 100 signifying total absolute, unreserved, or pervasive and enduring economic trust. 0 represents a complete absence of any form of trust between and among economic agents and actors.

1 divided by the index, 1 divided by T, I, would be the index of economic mistrust, of course.

So what is P?

The first variable. P is population size. The bigger the population, the easier it is to cheat and to deceive.

Because information is disseminated more slowly, peer pressure is limited, and reputational capital remains localized.

L, the next variable, law enforcement. Efficient law enforcement and a functioning judiciary enhance trust. The rule of law is critical.

C is corruption. Surprisingly, in the formula calculating the coefficient, corruption is a neutral effect.

On the one hand, it encourages preemptive mistrust by upsetting the level playing field.

On the other hand, corruption and venality increase certainty in otherwise uncertain economic environments by providing a tried and true price list for services.

Connectivity is the next variable. I, the most connected individuals are, the more connected individuals are.

And the faster the dissemination of accurate, transparent information, the higher the level of trust.

Technology such as the Internet serves to enhance economic trust. The less information friction there is, the higher the trust.

The next variable is S, stability and predictability. They are the cornerstones of economic trust.

Government intervention, geopolitical upheavals, crises, abrupt changes in accounting policies and tax laws, hyperinflation, institutional structural reform and other market deflecting events and processes all tend to reduce the average level of trust.

M is available in reliable price signals, not distorted by insider trading, stock manipulation, hoarding, informal economic activities, like market, gray market, monopolies, cartels, etc. This is M.

The next variable is V, a reliable store of value, a currency or goods and services that can serve as means of exchange and generate trust only when they represent real, long-term value.

So a value store is critical.

F, functioning institutions, they're crucial to the establishment and maintenance of trust. Financial intermediaries, banks, insurance companies, law enforcement agencies, courts, civil service, education institutions, their functioning predicates trust, creates trust.

R, cultural and social rationality. In all cultures and societies there are times when the optimization of profits and benefits, the ethics of contracting and otherwise rational economic behavior, they are all subordinated to often self-defeating, self-destructive, irrational beliefs, biases, prejudices and stereotypes.

Societies lapse into these irrational states, just look at Nazi Germany. And this is spurred on usually by capricious, ignorant, narcissistic, psychopathic or arbitrary leaders, by some malignancy of the ethos, by some change in mores.

And such surrealism is not conducive to economic trust.

In a nightmare environment one can hardly rely on a dream.

And wherewithal, the next variable is W, when all the economic actors and agents possess the liquidity and the knowledge necessary to complete their transactions and to honor their obligations.

And this creates and sustains an atmosphere of trust. It is impossible to exaggerate or overemphasize the critical role of trust.

And trust being a psychological trait, dimension, belief, value. It's not an economic thing. It's in the mind. It reflects expectations. It's volatile. It's lay- by. It's sometimes dysregulate. It reacts to external shocks, many of which, if not all of which, are not economic.

So there is trust mediates shocks. Trust brings shocks into the economic system, introduces shocks into the economic system.

Trust is the transmission mechanism of shocks. When an external shock happens, like a pandemic, the first thing to react is trust. Trust fluctuates or goes down.

It is through trust that changes in the behavior of economic agents and economic players take place. And these changes in behavior, in turn, have economic consequences.

So the economic consequences are the very last and not necessarily the most important link in a much longer chain, the bulk of which is actually psychological.

[ Pause ].

If you enjoyed this article, you might like the following:

Narcissist Trust Your Gut Feeling 4 Rules To Avoid Bad Relationships ( Intuition Explained)

Professor Sam Vaknin discusses the importance of intuition in relationships and decision-making. He explores different types of intuition, including idetic, emergent, and ideal intuition, and how they are used in various philosophical and psychological theories. He emphasizes the significance of intuition in understanding and navigating complex human interactions, particularly in dealing with narcissists and psychopaths.


Economics=Psychology+Counterfactual Models

Economics is not a science but rather a branch of psychology, as it deals with human behavior. Traditional economic theories and models fail to accurately predict and account for human irrationality, long-term investment horizons, and the role of innovation in growth and development. The field of behavioral economics is gaining traction as it combines psychology and economics, focusing on human cognition, emotions, and decision-making. To improve the field of economics, it should be treated as a branch of psychology, focusing on the complex and unpredictable nature of human beings.


Interrogate Your Partner: Their Past is Your Future

Professor Sam Vaknin advises that when considering a potential intimate partner, it is important to learn everything about their personal and sexual history. He suggests that you have the right to ask anything and everything, and your partner does not have the right to refuse to provide you with any information of a personal nature. Vaknin warns that people do not change, and the best predictor of future behavior is past behavior. Therefore, it is crucial to interrogate your potential partner thoroughly and methodically to protect yourself against future nasty surprises.


A-ha Moment, Gut Instinct, Insight, Knowledge, Intuition: Epistemology in Psychology

Professor Sam Vaknin discusses insight, intuition, gut instincts, aha moments, epiphanies, and their emotional and cognitive aspects. He explains that aha moments are emotional reactions to sudden insight and are usually preceded by a period of pondering and analyzing. Aha moments are crucial in psychotherapy as they lead to self-awareness and the ability to connect seemingly unrelated events. He also delves into the differences between motivation and knowledge, and the role of intuition and insight in psychotherapy. Additionally, he explores the need for emotions in inducing transformation and change, and the compensatory mechanisms used by individuals who lack insight. Furthermore, he touches on the epistemic value of theories and the role of epistemology in psychology.


Road to Riches: Behavioral Sales, Irrationality, and Choice

Sam Vaknin discusses the intersection of psychology and economics in sales, marketing, and advertising, emphasizing that human behavior is not always rational and is influenced by various psychological factors. He highlights the importance of understanding behavioral economics to improve sales strategies, mentioning experiments that demonstrate how context, presentation, and emotional responses significantly impact decision-making. Vaknin also touches on gender and age demographics in sales and the cognitive biases that affect how we perceive ourselves versus others.


How To Write a Case Study (CIAPS Class)

Professor Sam Vaknin discusses the importance and mechanics of creating a case study. He emphasizes the narrative and conclusion components, which include facts, context, theories, assumptions, analysis, criticism, and solutions. He also highlights the need to consider the audience and tailor the case study accordingly. The process involves fact gathering, contextualizing, identifying issues, and structuring the case study with an abstract, introduction, facts and findings, analysis and discussion, conclusions, limitations, and references. He also suggests referring to an essay on due diligence for further insights.


How You Recall Trauma (University Lecture)

Professor Sam Vaknin's lecture discusses the controversy surrounding false memories, particularly those related to abuse. He explores the debate over the accuracy of memories of trauma and the distinction between core memories and peripheral memories. He also delves into the concept of mentalism and mentalization, as well as the impact of therapy on memory recall. The lecture emphasizes the complexity and malleability of memory, and the potential for false memories to be implanted or constructed.


3 Ways To Navigate Your Life Via Spaces: Temporal, Imaginary, Social, Physical

The hippocampus is responsible for long-term memory, spatial perception, and social functioning. Recent studies have shown that it plays a crucial role in navigating social spaces and even music. The hippocampus is also involved in path integration, which involves keeping track of every stage of a journey to compute one's location. Additionally, the hippocampus encodes both time and distance, organizing physical and abstract spaces. The disruption of the ability to generate internal maps and spaces can lead to mental health disorders, such as narcissism.


Why I Remain Silent on Depp-Heard Trial (Interview in Superinteressante Magazine in Brazil)

Professor Sam Vaknin discusses the Johnny Depp and Amber Heard trial, stating that he will not comment on it as it is gossip and not academic. He criticizes mental health experts who have appeared on behalf of both parties, calling them unqualified. Vaknin then delves into the psychology of celebrity, explaining that celebrities fulfill emotional functions for fans, allowing them to indulge in wish fulfillment and daydreaming. However, when celebrities deviate from their prescribed roles, fans feel betrayed and humiliated, leading to a desire to punish and humiliate the celebrity.


Change Your Inner Dialog, Narrative Plot

Professor Sam Vaknin discusses the inner dialogue and its impact on our psyche. He explains that the voices in our heads are influenced by societal expectations and can lead to emotional dysregulation. Vaknin outlines the characteristics of a healthy inner dialogue and emphasizes the importance of understanding one's own happiness preconditions. He also warns against the dangers of becoming a narcissist or a psychopath in the process of rejecting societal influences.

Transcripts Copyright © Sam Vaknin 2010-2024, under license to William DeGraaf
Website Copyright © William DeGraaf 2022-2024
Get it on Google Play
Privacy policy